COMMUNITY ECONOMICS |
|||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Links to Other Subjects; Other Publications |
SUMMARYOne of the most controversial and often least understood operations of multinationals, transfer pricing, is clearly described and defined. An easily-followed illustration shows how transfer pricing can be used by multinationals to maximise their profits by tax avoidance and by obtaining tax rebates. Also discussed is the effect of transfer pricing on the tax burden carried by other tax payers. CONTENTS
Relevant Current and Associated Works Relevant Subject Index Pages and Site Overview TRANSFER PRICINGOne of the most controversial and often least understood of a multinational's operations is that of Transfer Pricing. When one part of a multinational organisation in one country transfers (that is, sells) goods, services or know-how to another part in another country, the price charged for these goods or services is called 'transfer price'. This may be a purely arbitrary figure, meaning by this that it may be unrelated to costs incurred, may be unrelated to operations carried out or to added value. We will see here that the transfer price can be set at a level which reduces or even cancels out the total tax which has to be paid by the multinational. Consider ourselves to be directors of the multinational. We are sitting in its boardroom at the head office in the home country of the multinational. The Finance Director is reviewing our operations.
He is talking about our trade with another company in another country. We are the parent company, they are one of our subsidiary companies. This means that they belong to us, that in the end we decide what they do and do not do, what happens to their profits. We, the parent company, are located in the 'home country'. The subsidiary company is located in another country, namely in the 'host country'. The Finance Director is simplifying the picture for our benefit: PAYING SOME TAXCase 1The subsidiary company buys goods at £100 each. They repack them and then export them from their country to our country, selling them to us at a price of £200 each. They are transferring them to us for a transfer price of £200. So they have made a profit of £200-£100=£100 and we are getting them at a price of £200. This case is illustrated by Figure 1 (Case 1). Having imported them at £200 each we sell them for £300 and thus make a profit of £300-£200=£100. Our overall profit is thus £100 in the subsidiary company's host country and another £100 in the multinational's home country, a total of £200. However, we need to consider the tax these companies have to pay on their profits, as the rates of tax (company or corporation tax) is different in the two countries. The subsidiary has to pay corporation tax of 20% of the £100 profit and so the tax amounts to £20. Our home-country corporation tax is 60% of the £100 profit, and so our tax amounts to £60. Overall, tax paid is £20+£60=£80 and this reduces our before-tax profit of £200 to an after-tax profit of £200-£80=£120. The subsidiary contributed £80 to this profit, while our own operations contributed £40. The after-tax profit generated by us, that is by the parent company in the home country, was smaller because we paid corporation tax of 60% which compares with the subsidiary's 20% All the numbers given so far are illustrated by Figure 1 (Case 1). Our Finance Director points out that as the overall after-tax profit is 40% of the selling price we should be pleased with the outcome. However, we can tell the subsidiary what to charge and can make the transfer price whatever we like. The transfer price is arbitrary, depending as it does only on agreement between ourselves and the subsidiary, and thus on ourselves. Case 2Consider Case 2 (see Figure 1). The transfer price is now £280 (compared with the previous £200). This has the effect of shifting before-tax profits from the parent company's home country (corporation tax 60%) to the subsidiary's host country (corporation tax 20%). Overall, we now pay less tax (£36+£12=£48) and as the before-tax profit is unchanged (£200), the after-tax profit becomes £200-£48=£152 and that is much more than the corresponding profit of £120 we made with a transfer price of £200. The subsidiary contributes £144 to this while our own contribution is £8. Our overall after-tax profit is now 51% of the selling price. Merely by changing the transfer price to an arbitrary higher figure of £280 we have increased our overall after-tax profit from £120 to £152, increased it by a staggering 27%. PAYING NO TAXCase 3As the transfer price is arbitrary, it can be £300 (see Figure 1, Case 3). This means that we are buying and selling at the same price of £300. Overall tax paid is now £40 and our after-tax profit becomes £160. The subsidiary contributes £160 to this while our own contribution is £0. So what we have done is to shift all our profits to the subsidiary and do not need to pay tax in the home country. But we need not stop there. The parent company can shift even more of its profits to the subsidiary. It can make a loss and this is illustrated by Case 4. GETTING TAX REPAYMENTSCase 4This case shows what happens if the transfer price is increased to £400. The subsidiary makes a profit of £300 and we make a loss of £100 on each item. This loss can be used by us to reduce our tax liability on other profitable operations carried out by the parent company in the home country. As a result we pay correspondingly less tax. The subsidiary pays corporation tax of £60 on their profits while we, the parent company, reduce our tax bill by £60, in effect getting a rebate of £60. Hence the overall result is that we pay no tax at all on this transaction and our after-tax profit becomes £200. We can take this one step further and make the Transfer Price £500 (see Case 5). Case 5The subsidiary now makes a profit of £400 and we make a loss of £200. The subsidiary pays corporation tax of £80 on their profits while we, the parent company, reduce our tax bill by £120, in effect getting a rebate of £120. Hence the overall result is that we get a tax rebate of £120 in the home country, pay £80 corporation tax in the host country, and are thus left with a tax rebate of £40 on this transaction. Adding this to our profit increases the after-tax profit from £200 to £240. TAX AVOIDANCETAX AVOIDANCE INCREASES PROFITSSo by increasing the purely arbitrary transfer price we doubled our after-tax profit, increasing it by 100%. This was done without any change to our procedures, operations or added value, was done by merely changing book entries. So where do these additional profits come from? They arise from tax avoidance. In other words it is possible for a multinational company to minimise its liability for corporation tax by transfer pricing. This is legal until governments legislate to prevent this practice. But note that in the cases we discussed, the tax paid to the host-country government increased, while the tax paid to the home-country government decreased, case by case. In other words, one government's loss is the other government's gain. So one government can be expected to want to legislate against unfair transfer pricing practices, while the other government can be expected to object to, and to resist, such legislation. TAX AVOIDANCE TRANSFERS THE TAX OBLIGATIONThe parent company operates in the home country. The government of that country or state spend money on behalf of its citizens - providing education, health care, social security, protection against crime and security against attack from outside. It collects much of the money it needs from citizens and companies by means of a tax on income - those who earn most pay most, those who earn least pay least. This tax is called Corporation Tax when it is collected from companies (corporations) and Income Tax when it is collected from individuals. Say a multinational has increased its profits by tax avoidance. As the government's expenses have not changed it must make up this shortfall elsewhere. From its other tax payers, say from its citizens. So its citizens pay more tax, the government can now spend the same amount as before, the multinational's profits have increased. In other words, the multinational's increased profits arise from money which is in effect collected by the government by taxation from its taxpayers. The multinational, and this means the owners and directors of the multinational, are thus in effect taxing the people and in this way increasing the multinational's profits and thus their own incomes and wealth. A matter far removed from earning reasonable profits from providing needed quality goods and services at reasonable prices in open competition with other corporations. Many multinationals have grown to a size where they threaten or dominate the economic and financial independence and well-being of many countries. Multinationals are accountable to their directors and owners for profitability and growth instead of being accountable to elected representatives of the people for acting for or against the national interest. Studies published in the USA, for example, tell us much about the extent to which multinationals can avoid paying tax on their profits. These present a disturbing picture. It seems that at times some top companies pay no federal income tax or obtain an overall rebate. Tax allowances appear to add well over $100bn each year to the accounts of US corporations, and are thus given to owners and directors. It has become common knowledge that multinational enterprises can operate against national interests. That multinationals <1> can gain so much profit from tax avoidance, that is from in effect taxing the population, is a case in point. Multinationals need to be made accountable to elected representatives of the people, for their policies and for acting for or against the national interest. NOTES
Relevant Current and Associated Works
RELEVANT SUBJECT INDEX PAGESOther Subjects; Other PublicationsThe Site Overview page has links to all individual Subject Index Pages which between them list the works by Manfred Davidmann which are available on the Internet, with short descriptions and links for downloading. To see the Site Overview page, click Overview |
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
Copyright © Manfred Davidmann 1991, 1996, 2006
History Updated 2021:
|